Response to consultation on remuneration of sales staff

Go back

1) Do you agree with Guideline 1 on design?

Similar to what ESMA referred to in its ‘Guidelines on remuneration policies and practices (MiFID)’ (para 13, p. 21), para. 1.1. (p. 18) of the EBA’s draft guidelines states that “the institution should design and implement remuneration policies that take into account the rights and interest of consum-ers and [...].” We would like to point out that consumer interest is not immutable, but constantly changing. Therefore, we would like to advise not to pursue a too rigid and inflexible concept of con-sumer protection.

Para. 1.7 (p. 18-19) states that “[…] the institution should ensure that the ratio between the fixed and variable components of the remuneration is appropriately balanced [...]”. Since this is an obligation already anchored in Art. 94 Capital Requirements Directive IV (CRD IV), we do not fully understand why it is repeated in the draft guidelines. This may give rise to confusion.

Speaking about the coherence with corporate social responsibility (CSR) policies, we believe that the design proposed by the draft guidelines is coherent; in particular, the aspects related to consumer rela-tionships. Consumers are among the main interest groups of, particularly, retail banks, and consumer relationships are therefore often one of the central cornerstones of banks’ CSR policies. The latter include, inter alia, consumer protection, consumer satisfaction and the objective of fair relations with consumers in the forefront of their commercial strategies.



Remuneration policies have close relations with CSR policies and are expected to reward:
 The protection of consumers’ interests. It would be counterproductive to reward mis-selling or an employee’s performance that goes against a consumer’s interest. This would break the needed and essential trust of the consumer base in the bank;
 Long-standing relationships with clients as this will provide a solid base for growth and inno-vation. Long-term perspectives are indeed essential to CSR policies;
 Quality and satisfaction. What if a bank’s staff did not provide clients with adequate products and services? What if mis-selling was incentivised and therefore non-performing loan rates in-creased? This would certainly not be good for the bank or the consumer.

In conclusion, it would, in ESBG’s opinion, not be advisable to see CSR and remuneration policies as two completely separate areas. On top of this, the three above mentioned points are not only topics which are relevant for CSR and remuneration policies, but, more generally, essential to the commer-cial success of a retail bank. Based on this, in our view, it is of great importance that (i) the remunera-tion incentives are aligned with the consumer interest, (ii) a long-term relationship with consumers is promoted and (iii) other qualitative factors such as consumer satisfaction are adequately taken into account.

With regard to para 1.8 (page 19), ESBG would like to underline that, while neither incentive schemes nor sanctions that could lead to mis-selling or excessive risk taking are desirable, an institu-tion must be able to make performance based staffing decisions.

Apart from this, ESBG believes that the requirements set out in para 1.9 (page 19) are somewhat contradictory with the requirements quoted in CRD IV and in the draft guidelines, which state that, when developing remuneration policies, other factors next to quantitative criteria should also be con-sidered. More factors naturally increase complexity in remuneration policies.

3) Do you agree with Guideline 3 on approval and monitoring?

In line with our response to question one, ESBG considers that, in the design of the remuneration policies, CSR-related aspects are already taken into account in an appropriate manner in order to as-sure an advantageous coherence between remuneration and CSR policies (regarding consumer rela-tionships).

4) Do you see a need for any additional requirements?

No. In principle, ESBG is fine with this general wording of the rules as, in practice, some room for interpretation is needed in order to consider the special situation of each credit institution and the needs of the consumers.

5) Do you have any other comments?

As indicated above, it is important, in ESBG’s view, to incentivise long-term relationships with con-sumers that also include qualitative aspects, e.g. satisfaction indicators, confidence in financial insti-tutions, the adequacy of the products with their necessities, etc.

Apart from this, we have the impression that the risks outlined in the impact assessment, unfortunate-ly, do not consider an important issue that could potentially arise, in our opinion: the cost for finan-cial institutions of non-incentivised staff.

As long as the mis-selling is adequately prevented and consumers are fairly treated, we believe that adequate incentives for sales staff to maximize their performance (also in monetary terms for the fi-nancial institution) should, in principle, not be an issue. Even though the EBA’s draft guidelines seem to consider this point to some extent, a lack of clarity should be avoided in order to preserve the fi-nancial entities’ capability to incentivise their staff without assuming regulatory risks.

As an example of the lack of certainty mentioned, it should be noted that the draft guidelines state that qualitative and quantitative criteria should be considered for determining the level of variable remuneration. However, in the ‘Background and Rationale’ section, it is stated (page 8) that accelera-tor features and rankings should be prevented, without considering that mixing them with the ade-quate qualitative criteria would lead to the result that consumers’ rights and interests are taken ade-quately into account while not abolishing incentivised staff.

Very similarly, the ‘Background and Rationale’ section refers to the proportionality principle (page 9). However, it seems that the principle is not very well mirrored regarding the small part of incentive-based remuneration in relation to the fixed income. While we fully agree that no reward aspects should lead to the taking of irresponsible risk and/or the mis-selling of banking products, we would also like to share our view that very small incentive-based remuneration sums (e.g. an incentive that represents a very low percentage of the fixed remuneration of an employee) are usually not a driver for a risk of mis-selling and disregarding consumers’ interest (i.e. not applying an entity’s internal cri-teria, nor an employee’s knowledge and experience in banking sales). In this regard, the EBA’s opin-ion (on proportionality) referred to above needs to be taken appropriately into account, as the ra-tionale applying to remuneration provisions in the CRD IV should be followed in the EBA guidelines on remuneration of the sales staff of banking products as well.

On a side note, it is, in ESBG’s view, important to stress in all remuneration-related guidelines that “the remuneration of staff in general, and of persons directly offering or providing products or ser-vices to consumers in particular, is an important means by which financial institutions attract, moti-vate and retain employees with the skills needed for the institution’s success” (page 5). Consequently, we would like to underline the fact that in the future the management of a bank should still be al-lowed to lead the sales staff partly on the basis of sales figures. For instance, financial incentives for meeting sales targets could remain possible on a team level, while, in a second step, out of this team pool the bonus for the individual employee would be designed based not only on the sales figures but also on the economic situation of the company and qualitative criteria for the individual, such as cus-tomer satisfaction, risk costs, etc.

In this sense, it should not be seen as a risk for the costumers that a financial institution organises competitions where members of staff of relevant persons are incentivised to outperform their peers, in order for them to receive financial or non-financial remuneration. Adequately mixed with qualitative criteria, incentivising employees to outperform their peers is the only manner to promote them in their professional career, irrespective of the economic sector in which the employer operates.

In conclusion, ESBG would like to point to the occasional lack of certainty and clarity in order to avoid that the guidelines’ application leads to unwanted consequences for incentivised staff. We don’t see any compatibility issues with the aims of the draft guidelines in this respect. Despite the fact that the CRD IV is a good source and basis, ESBG suggests adding an Annex (or examples) to the draft guidelines that provides safe harbours to financial institutions regarding the adequate balance of con-sumer protection and incentivised staff. The proportionality principle and the possibility to use in-struments like accelerator features and rankings – adequately mixed with quantitative criteria (e.g. based on the number and content of complaints received) – should thereby be borne in mind. Other-wise, in order to avoid the risk of not complying with the guidelines, the number of incentivised staff in financial entities would decrease significantly. This, as a consequence, would make financial insti-tutions unable to attract, motivate and retain employees with the skills needed for their success.

Upload files

Name of organisation

European Savings and Retail Banking Group (ESBG)